P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 526 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development BOX 15-1. THE HAWALA SYSTEM Stateless and nomadic peoples and those living amid war often design alternative systems to those of banks, credit cards, and travelers’ checks. According to Peter Little (2003:142) In the Somali borderlands, confidence in the local currency facilitates credit and financial transfers, critical components of commerce because of the risks associated with [traders and herders] carrying large amounts of cash. While much of the livestock trade is calculated in SoSh [the Somalia shilling issued in the 1980s] and final payments are made in SoSh or US dollars, the actual handling of cash in large transactions is minimal. Somali border traders … can take their earnings to Nairobi, convert them to dollars, and then “wire” them back to money houses in Somalia, where they can be picked up by associates. This informal hawala system avoids the carrying of large amounts of cash across the border. Informal money houses and middlemen, important in long-distance trade involving livestock, mediate credit in a system that requires considerable trust to operate. The Somali shilling, because of its relative stability, facilitated border trade in livestock and other commodities in a weak state that lacked a central bank (Little 2003:142, 145). Unfortunately for many Somalis, the largest hawala bank, al Barakat, was abruptly closed in November 2001 by a U.S.-led initiative that claimed the bank laun- dered funds for al-Qaida. Thus, what had evolved as a viable institution for trans- fers following the collapse of Somalia’s finance sector was closed to thousands of Somali families dependent on it in the region and around the world (Little 2003: 143). The weaknesses of banks and other financial institutions impose substantial trans- actions costs on migrants who send remittances. The average cost of these transfers (exchange-rate commissions and transfers fees) are 12.8 percent in Cuba, 12.6 per- cent in Colombia, 10.7 percent in Haiti, and 9.1 percent in Mexico, an astronomical sum compared with transfers among DCs. Many U.S. banks recognize matriculas consulares , identity cards for legal or illegal residents with Mexican citizenship, as identification for opening bank accounts (World Bank 2003f:165–166). The exorbitant transfer cost has increased the use of informal channels, such as the hawala (“transfer” in Arabic) (Little 2003:143; World Bank 2003f:173). However, in an era of concern about money laundering by terrorists, the hawala option has been increasingly cut off, as Box 15-1 indicates. PRIVATE INVESTMENT AND MULTINATIONAL CORPORATIONS As real aid to less-developed countries fell during the 1990s, foreign direct investment (FDI), at 74 percent in 2002, comprised an increasing portion of total resource flows to developing countries (Figure 15-1). Private FDI, a source for financing the balance P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 15. Balance of Payments, Aid, and Foreign Investment 527 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1998 1982 A ll c o u ntries C anada M e x i c o C hina Other A sia FIGURE 15-8. Exports of U.S. Affiliates as a Share of Total Exports (in percent). Note: Exports from U.S. affiliates in all countries show no rise in the share of sales because of declines in the export shares in primary production. Source: World Bank 2000f:58. on goods and services deficit, consists of portfolio investment , in which the investor has no control over operations, and direct investment , which entails managing the operations. In the 19th century, Western European investment in the young growing debtor nations, the United States and Canada, was primarily portfolio investment, such as securities. Today, DC investment in LDCs is mostly private direct investment. Multinational corporations (MNCs), business firms with a parent company in one country and subsidiary operations in other countries, are responsible for much of this direct investment. MNC intrafirm trade is a large proportion of international trade. In 1999, 36 per- cent of U.S. exports were intrafirm exports, whereas in Japan 31 percent of exports were intrafirm, for both countries an increase over 1990’s percentage. Intrafirm trade in services became steadily more important during the last quarter of the 20th century. In addition, LDCs boosted exports by participating in global production networks dominated by DCs such as the United States and Japan. Exports of U.S. affiliates as a percentage of China’s exports were 36 percent in 1998. Figure 15-8 shows U.S. affiliate percentages in other Asian countries, Mexico, Canada, and all countries with U.S. affiliates in 1982 and 1998. At the turn of the 21st century, the global economy was dominated by MNCs from the United States, European Union, and Japan. DCs comprised 71 percent of foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows, 75 percent of FDI outflows, and a large share of the international trade. But emerging economies such as Taiwan, South Korea, Singapore, China, India, and Brazil are beginning to be a factor in foreign investment (D’Costa 2003:3l; Table 15-3). Moreover, as Figure 15-9 shows, in 2000, 56 percent of the FDI in LDCs is from high-income OECD countries compared to 35 percent from other LDCs, and 9 percent from high-income non-OECD countries. H igh - in c ome non - O ECD /total FD I North - So u th FD I/total FDI So u th - So u th FD I/total FDI FIGURE 15-9. Share of South–South FDI in Total FDI. Source: World Bank 2003f:124. P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 528 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development TABLE 15-3. Outward FDI Flows, a by Geographical Destination, 1999–2001 (billions of dollars and percentage distribution) Value in billion dollars Percentage distribution Average Average Region/economy 1999–2000 2001 1999–2000 2001 Developed countries 924.2 470.1 83.7 74.6 Western Europe 640.9 259.7 58.0 41.2 European Union 589.4 236.6 53.4 37.5 Other Western Europe 50.9 24.1 4.6 3.8 Unspecified Western Europe 0.6 − 1.0 0.1 − 0.2 North America 256.2 197.3 23.2 31.3 Other developed countries 25.0 9.1 2.3 1.4 Unspecified developed countries 2.2 3.9 0.2 0.6 Developing economies 129.2 115.2 11.7 18.3 Africa 6.8 8.5 0.6 1.3 North Africa 0.5 1.8 0.0 0.3 Other Africa 5.0 6.3 0.5 1.0 Unspecified Africa 1.3 0.4 0.1 0.1 Latin America and the Caribbean 84.7 69.1 7.7 11.0 South America 39.5 20.3 3.6 3.2 Other Latin America and Caribbean 36.4 38.0 3.3 6.0 Unspecified Latin America and Caribbean 8.8 10.9 0.8 1.7 Asia 33.9 36.5 3.1 5.8 West Asia 0.8 2.8 0.1 0.4 Central Asia 1.0 0.1 0.1 0.0 South, East, and South-East Asia 31.0 32.8 2.8 5.2 Unspecified Asia 1.1 0.8 0.1 0.1 The Pacific 1.5 0.8 0.1 0.1 Unspecified developing countries 2.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 Central and Eastern Europe 18.0 18.6 1.6 3.0 Unspecified 32.7 26.3 3.0 4.2 Total world 1,104.1 630.3 100.0 100.0 May not add up to totals because of rounding. a Totals for developed countries are based on data for the following countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium and Luxembourg, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Iceland, Ireland, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, and United States. Source: UNCTAD 2003:9. P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 15. Balance of Payments, Aid, and Foreign Investment 529 The United States accounted for 52 percent of the world’s stock of outward foreign direct investment (FDI) capital in 1971, 40 percent in 1983, 25 percent in 1993, and 16 percent in 2001. DCs comprised 97 percent of world FDI capital stock in 1983 and 93 percent in 1993, but fell to 75 percent in 2001. The United States was the leading source of outward FDI from 1971 to 2001 although the European Union, with 38 percent, had more than twice the US’s 2001 figure. The leading countries of the South with FDI stock included DCs Singapore, Taiwan, South Korea, and Hong Kong, in addition to South Africa, India, Brazil, Argentina, Colombia, Peru, the Philippines, and the OPEC countries (Bergsten, Horst, and Moran 1981:267–95; Streeten 1981:308–15; Dunning 1988:28–29; UNCTAD 1994; UNCTAD 2003:6–9). The United States had both the largest inward (Table 15-4) and outward flows of foreign direct investment in 2001. 10 When Hong Kong is included, China ranked second in 2001 in inward flows (or first in LDC inflows). Although some FDI flowing to China is recycled domestic investment (explained in Chapter 19), even if this were subtracted, China’s FDI inflows would rank first among LDCs. The world’s potentially largest market and low-cost labor-intensive production in China, which has become the world’s major industrial workshop, attracted many MNCs. Most of the world’s business community believed that no one could afford to ignore the enormous investment opportunities in China. For many an MNC, investment in China represented an effort to get its “foot in the door.” But China, a low-cost source, is a hard bargainer, frequently demanding total access to foreign technology in exchange for access to its market (Kranhold 2004:A1). Still, China’s FDI growth for the first two decades of the 21st century will depend largely on its political stability, the consistency of its economic policies, its macroeconomic management, and its integration into the world economy (UNCTAD 1994b:14–68). Mexico and Brazil were other leading FDI hosts in developing countries. If we use UNCTAD definitions of LDCs, which include Singapore, Republic of Korea, and Taiwan, and if Hong Kong is combined with China, the top 10 FDI recipients among developing economies received 73 percent of inward FDI in 2001. UNC- TAD (2002b:215) states that private capital flows have been concentrated in a few countries. Africa, where the risk premium is high, received only 19 percent. Most of the leading African recipients – Angola, Nigeria, Algeria, Chad, Tunisia, South Africa, Sudan, Egypt, Morocco, and Mozambique – received large amounts of FDI in minerals or petroleum (UNCTAD 2003:7–13, 34). The World Bank (1997a:2) states that “participation in the global production networks established by multinational enterprises provides developing countries with new means to enhance their economic performance by accessing global know-how and expanding their integration into world markets.” Indeed, net private capital flows to LDCs were $168 billion or 2.8 percent of their GNI in 2001, a fall from 10 The drop in inflows to the United States reflected large repayments of loans by foreign affiliates in the United States to their parent companies and reductions in financing mergers and acquisitions in the United States. Much of the inflow to Luxembourg, separated from Belgium for the first time in 2002, was driven by tax advantages rather than productivity (UNCTAD 2003:6–8, 31). P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 530 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development TABLE 15-4. FDI Inflows to Major Economies, 2001 and 2002 (billions of dollars) Host region/economy 2001 2002 World 823.8 651.2 Developed countries 589.4 460.3 European Union 389.4 374.4 France 55.2 51.5 Germany 33.9 38.0 Luxembourg − 125.6 United Kingdom 62.0 24.9 Other EU 238.3 134.4 United States 144.0 30.0 Other 56.0 55.9 Developing economies 209.4 162.1 Africa 18.8 11.0 Algeria 1.2 1.1 Angola 2.1 1.3 Nigeria 1.1 1.3 South Africa 6.8 0.8 Other Africa 7.6 6.5 Latin America and the Caribbean 83.7 56.0 Argentina 3.2 1.0 Brazil 22.5 16.6 Mexico 25.3 13.6 Other Latin America 32.7 24.8 Asia and the Pacific 106.9 95.1 China 46.8 52.7 Hong Kong, China 23.8 13.7 India 3.4 3.4 Korea, Republic of 3.5 2.0 Malaysia 0.6 3.2 Philippines 1.0 1.1 Singapore 10.9 7.7 Taiwan Province of China 4.1 1.4 Thailand 3.8 1.1 Other Asia and Pacific 9.0 8.8 Transitional economies 25.0 28.7 Central and Eastern Europe 25.0 28.7 Czech Republic 5.6 9.3 Poland 5.7 4.1 Russian Federation 2.5 2.4 Other C. & E. Europe 11.2 12.9 May not add up to totals because of rounding. Categories of developed, developing, and transitional economies may vary from those in this book. Source: UNCTAD 2003:7. P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 15. Balance of Payments, Aid, and Foreign Investment 531 this percentage in 1990. This percentage fell even further for low-income countries, many with low credit ratings during this period, a continuation of a fall that began in the early 1980s (World Bank 2003h:16, 332; FitzGerald 2002:62–84). In addition, private capital flows are highly volatile, especially in countries that have liberalized their financial markets. After the 1997–98 Asian crisis, for example, private capital flows to LDCs fell substantially. Although subject to substantial fluctuations, about half of private capital flows to LDCs in the 1990s were loans, which contribute to future debt service, and portfo- lio investments, which are subject to reverse capital flows (World Bank 2002e:354; UNCTAD 2003d:4). FDI does not generate debt servicing or capital outflows, and potentially can finance a savings or balance of payments deficit, bring about a trans- fer of technology and innovative methods of increasing productivity, fill part of the shortage of high-level skills, provide training for domestic managers and technicians, generate tax revenue from income and corporate profits tax, and complement local entrepreneurship by subcontracting to ancillary industries, component makers, or repair shops, or by creating forward and backward linkages. Investment inflows as a percentage of gross fixed capital investment in Africa were 9 percent in 2002. However, although annual FDI flows to least developed countries increased by 65 percent from 1989 to 1994, and tripled from 1989 to 2001 (Fig- ure 15-10) the least-developed countries’ share of developing-country inflows was only 0.6 per cent in 2001. Most of these flows were to African mineral and petroleum countries (UNCTAD 2002c:49, 74, 77). Moreover, low-income countries (LICs) com- prised only 30 percent of the $171 billion FDI flows to developing countries of 2001, and India took a lion’s share of LIC’s FDI (World Bank 2003e:87; World Bank 2003h: 331–332). 11 The share of FDI flows in 1998–2000 gross domestic capital formation was 7 percent for LLDCs and 13 percent for all other developing countries. According to UNCTAD (2002c:73–78), 17 of the 25 LLDCs for which indexes were constructed were underperformers, 1986–2001, in attracting FDI flows. Developing countries, particularly LLDCs, need policies to increase FDI and other external resources. In 1988, the World Bank established the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (MIGA) to help developing countries attract foreign investment. MIGA provides investors with marketing services, legal advise, and guarantees against noncommercial risk, such as expropriation and war (Aguilar 1997:10). By 2001, 41 least-developed countries had concluded bilateral investment treaties (BITs) with other countries for the protection and promotion of foreign investment, and 33 had entered into double taxation treaties to avoid taxation in both LLDC and the headquarters’ country. FDI plays a role not only in finance but also in skills, technology, and knowledge needed to spur economic growth (ibid., pp. 78–79). 11 Ndikumana (2001) contends that reports of a “surge” in Africa’s FDI is an illusion. Africa’s share of FDI inflows to LDCs fell from 10.5 percent in 1981–89 to 4.3 percent in 1999. Reasons for this fall were a weak macroeconomic environment, underdeveloped financial system (including weak regulation and supervision), and high country risk from high transactions cost from administrative inefficiency and psychocultural distance. P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 532 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development FIGURE 15-10. FDI Inflows and ODA Flows to LLDCs, 1985–2001 (billions of dollars) . Source: UNCTAD 2002d:77. Although official development assistance comprised the largest component of exter- nal resources for LLDCs, it declined relatively and absolutely, 1995 to 2000 (see Figure 15-10). Tanzania, an LLDC, provided an enabling framework for FDI in the late 1980s and early 1990s, by making the transition to a market economy, undertaking market reforms (including enacting a mining act more favorable to FDI), and beginning a privatization program for inefficient state enterprises. During 1995–2000, Tanzania received $1 billion FDI, much in gold mining, compared to only $90 million during 1989–94. Mining served as an engine of growth, helping to increase gold exports and to modernize the banking industry. Foreign investors have helped restructure privatized enterprises, boosting technology, skills, and competitiveness. In addition, from the early to late 1990s, FDI’s contribution to the balance of payments changed from negative to positive (UNCTAD 2002c:75). Similar to Tanzania, there is a possibility of attracting FDI to LLDCs and low- income countries, not just to those with potentially large markets, such as China and India; with nonresident nationals, as China or India; with resident nationals man- aging cross-border investments, as in Malaysia, Mozambique, South Africa, or East Africa (FitzGerald 2002:71); or with extractive industries, such as Nigeria or Angola. Vietnam introduced FDI legislation in 1987–88, which, together with the lifting of U.S. economic sanctions in 1994, increased FDI inflows from $8 million in 1988 to $150 million in 1995. Bangladesh’s FDI reforms in 1991, which facilitated the estab- lishment of foreign-owned subsidiaries, increased inflows from just a trickle in the 1980s to $125 million in 1995. Ghana, as a result of Ashanti goldfield privatization, increased annual FDI inflows 17-fold from a $11.7 million average during 1986–92 to an average of $201 million in 1993–95 (ODI 1997:2). Even Cambodia, which created a legal framework and the necessary institutions to promote FDI after 1993, increased its FDI capital inflows from virtually nothing in 1990 to $656 million in 1996 (UNCTAD 1997a:54, 316). P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 15. Balance of Payments, Aid, and Foreign Investment 533 Since the mid-1980s, with falling trade, transport, and communication barriers, multinational corporations (MNCs) have increased their international outsourcing, importing components from low-cost production locations abroad and exporting to overseas assembly or processing locations. As an example, following the rise of the yen after 1985, Japan’s major electronics manufacturers outsourced assembly and other final stages of output to Asian countries (World Bank 1997i:42–43). Asian NICs and ASEAN countries were a part of Japanese companies’ borderless economic system of trade and investment. These companies used a flying-geese pattern, with Japan at the lead, and Asian emerging nations forming the “V” behind. Chapter 17 discusses both Japanese and U.S. global production networks. Developing countries need to undertake major institutional changes (see Chap- ter 4), not only to facilitate foreign and domestic investment but to provide the scaf- folding for other economic policies that increase a country’s attractiveness for foreign private domestic capital flows. With changes in institutions, a number of low-income countries could begin participating in the new international division of labor cre- ated by outsourcing by high-income OECD countries. But this flying-geese pattern may also apply to non-OECD leader countries. ECA (1989) estimates that, dur- ing the 1980s, Southern African Development Community (SADC) countries other than South Africa lost one-fourth of their GDP from South Africa’s destabilization. However, since 1994, a democratic and prosperous South Africa should provide the economic leadership to spur SADC’s economic development. South Africa, with its trade and FDI (including those by MNCs in the country), could serve as a “growth pole” for other SADC members of the region – Angola, Botswana, Lesotho, Malawi, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Swaziland, Tanzania, Zambia, and Zimbabwe (UNCTAD 1997b:64–66). Of course, participating in this global production sharing has its benefits and costs, as in the cases of Malaysia and Thailand, discussed in Chapter 17, and also discussed later when we look at the benefits and costs of MNCs. THE BENEFITS AND COSTS OF MULTINATIONAL CORPORATIONS Some LDC governments are ambivalent, or even hostile, toward MNCs. To be sure, these corporations bring in capital, new technology, management skills, new prod- ucts, and increased efficiency and income; however, MNCs usually seek to maximize the profits of the parent company, rather than the subsidiaries’. Surely the main rea- son for LDCs soliciting MNC investment and other foreign direct investment is their contribution to technology transfer. 12 However, it may be in the interest of the parent company to limit the transfer of technology and industrial secrets to local personnel of the subsidiary, to restrict its exports, to force it to purchase intermediate parts and capital goods from the parent, and to set intrafirm (but international) transfer prices to shift taxes from the host country. Still, during the last decade or so, some MNCs have concentrated increasing research and development in affiliates, even in LDCs. 12 Javorcik (2004:605–627) finds positive productivity spillovers from FDI from foreign affiliates to their local suppliers (that is, backward linkages) but only with partially owned foreign projects. P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 534 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development For example, in the 1990s, when U.S., Japanese, and E.U. MNC affiliates became more integrated into parent companies’ highly nuanced value added ladder, MNCs located more research and development (R&D) in their affiliates. Most foreign investment is from large corporations. The largest MNCs, with hun- dreds of branches and affiliates throughout the world, have an output comparable to the LDC with which they bargain. ExxonMobile, Shell, BP, General Motors, Ford, Toyota, Hitachi, Matsushita, Siemens, and General Electric each have an annual value added exceeding that of most third-world countries (Table 15-5). Thus, for instance, General Motors would not negotiate investment in Bangladesh or ExxonMobile in Nigeria as an inferior party but as roughly an equal in economic power and size. 13 Furthermore, MNCs are increasingly footloose, shifting investments from country to another as tax rates, wages, and other costs change (Barnet and Cavanagh 1994). MNCs are important actors on the international scene. UNCTAD estimates that the value added of the world’s top 100 firms accounted for 4.3 percent of world GDP in 2000 (UNCTAD 2002:91) and that MNC intrafirm trade was one-third of inter- national trade (UNCTAD 1994b). Four-fifths of Africa’s 1983 commodity trade was handled by MNCs. Thirty-eight percent of total U.S. imports in 1977 consisted of intrafirm transactions by MNCs based in the United States. Over one-third of these transactions were from LDCs. Moreover, MNCs play an important role in LDC manufacturing exports, responsible for 20 percent of Latin America’s manufactured exports. Indeed, U.S. affiliates alone accounted for 7.2 percent of 1977 LDC manu- facturing exports, 35.7 percent of Mexico’s, and 15.2 percent in Brazil, but only 1.5 percent in South Korea (UNCTAD Seminar Program 1978; Streeten 1981:308–315; Economic Commission for Africa 1983a; UNCTAD 1985:3–8; Blomstrom, Kraus, and Lipsey 1988). The markets MNCs operate in are often international oligopolies with compe- tition among few sellers whose pricing decisions are interdependent. International economists contend that large corporations invest overseas because of international imperfections in the market for goods, resources, or technology. The MNCs benefit from monopoly advantages, such as patents, technical knowledge, superior manage- rial and marketing skills, better access to capital markets, economies of large-scale production, and economies of vertical integration (that is, cost savings from decision coordination between a producing unit and its upstream suppliers and its down- stream buyers). An example of vertical integration is from crude petroleum marketing backward to its drilling and forward to consumer markets for its refined products. UNCTAD (1993:5) argues, however, that in the 1990s, with substantial improve- ments in communication and information technologies, MNCs have moved to even more complex integration, coordinating “a growing number of activities in a wider array of locations.” Multinationals are increasingly establishing stand-alone affili- ates, linked by ownership to the parent but otherwise operating largely as independent 13 Table 15-5 subtracts purchases of inputs from other firms from, for example, General Motor’s pro- duction to get value added, to avoid double-counting the production of inputs supplied by one firm to another. This makes the figure for GM comparable to Bangladesh’s GDP. The table’s notes indicate the adjustment made to sales to obtain value added, an adjustment that, at best, indicates a rough comparability between MNCs and nation-states. P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 15. Balance of Payments, Aid, and Foreign Investment 535 TABLE 15-5. Ranking of Developing (Low- and Middle-Income) Countries and Multinational Corporations According to Value Added in 2000 a ($ billions) 1. China 1,080 2. Brazil 595 3. Mexico 575 4. India 457 5. Argentina 285 6. Russian Federation 251 7. Turkey 200 8. Saudi Arabia 173 9. Poland 158 10. Indonesia 153 11. South Africa 126 12. Thailand 122 13. Venezuela 120 14. Iran, Islamic Rep. of 105 15. Egypt 99 16. Malaysia 90 17. Colombia 81 18. Philippines 75 19. Chile 71 20. Exxon Mobile b 63 21. Pakistan 62 22. General Motors b 56 23. Peru 53 24. Algeria 53 25. Bangladesh 47 26. Hungary 46 27. Ford Motor 44 28. Daimler Chrysler 42 29. Nigeria 41 30. General Electric b 39 31. Toyota Motor b 38 32. Kuwait 38 33. Romania 37 34. Royal Dutch/Shell 36 35. Morocco 33 36. Ukraine 32 37. Siemens 32 38. Viet Nam 31 39. Libyan Arab Jamahiriya 31 40. BP 30 41. Wal-Mart Stores c 30 42. IBM b 27 43. Volkswagen 24 44. Cuba 24 (continued) P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 536 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development TABLE 15-5 (continued) 45. Hitachi b 24 46. Total FinaElf 23 47. Verizon Communications d 23 48. Matsushita Electric Industrial b 22 49. Mitsui & Company c 20 50. E. On 20 51. Oman 20 52. Sony b 20 53. Mitsubishi c 20 54. Uruguay 20 55. Dominican Republic 20 56. Tunisia 19 57. Philip Morris b 19 58. Slovakia 19 59. Croatia 19 60. Guatemala 19 61. SBC Communications d 19 62. Itochu c 18 63. Kazakhstan 18 64. Honda Motor b 18 65. Eni 18 66. Nissan Motor b 18 67. Toshiba b 17 68. Syrian Arab Republic 17 69. GlaxoSmithKline 17 70. BT 17 Note: Thirty high-income countries (see cover) were omitted from the table. a GDP for countries and value added for MNCs. Value-added is defined as the sum of salaries, pretax profits, and depreciation and amortization. b Value-added is estimated by applying the 30 percent share of value- added in the total sales, 2000, of manufacturers for which the data were available. c Value-added is estimated by applying the 16 percent share of value- added in the total sales, 2000, of trading companies for which the data on value-added were available. d Value-added is estimated by applying the 37 percent share of value- added in the total sales, 2000, of other tertiary companies for which the data on value-added were available. Source: UNCTAD 2002c:90–91. concerns within the host economy. These affiliates arrange their own subcontractors, suppliers, and marketing, with some even located in third countries. From 1988 to 1992, LDCs, under pressure by creditors to privatize public enter- prises, sold 17 percent of their medium-sized and large state-owned enterprises to foreign direct investors. In Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union, 1988 to P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 15. Balance of Payments, Aid, and Foreign Investment 537 1992, FDI from privatizing state-owned enterprises comprised 67 percent of total FDI inflows to that region (UNCTAD 1994b:26). Additionally, in some industries, control over global marketing and financing still gives MNCs much power in determining the supply and price of LDC primary exports. For example, three conglomerates account for 70–75 percent of the global banana market; six corporations, 70 percent of cocoa trade; and six MNCs, 85–90 percent of leaf tobacco trade (Economic Commission for Africa 1983a). Yet, ironically in some instances, MNCs may increase competition because their intrafirm transactions break down barriers to free trade and factor movement between countries. By contrast, once MNCs are established in an economy, they may exploit their monopolistic advantages and enhance concentration. Thus, MNCs, which accounted for 62 percent of manufacturing’s capital stock in Nigeria in 1965, contributed to high rates of industrial concentration. Yet a subsidiary’s production that dominates a LDC industry may be only a fraction of the parent company’s output and peripheral to the MNC’s decision-making process (Kindleberger 1974:267–285; Nafziger 1977:55–60). You may have already sensed that leaders in LDCs do not agree on whether MNCs are beneficial or not. Some emphasize that MNCs provide scarce capital and advanced technology essential for rapid growth. Others believe such dependence for capital and technology hampers development. In the next two sections, we summarize the benefits and costs of MNCs in less-developed countries. 14 The benefits of MNCs. MNCs can help the developing country to 1. Finance a savings gap or balance of payments deficit. 2. Acquire a specialized good or service essential for domestic production (for exam- ple, an underwater engineering system for offshore oil drilling or computer capa- bility for analyzing the strength and weight of a dam’s components). 3. Obtain foreign technology and innovative methods of increasing productivity. 4. Generate appropriate technology by adapting existing processes or by means of a new invention. 5. Fill part of the shortage in management and entrepreneurship. 6. Complement local entrepreneurship by subcontracting to ancillary industries, component makers, or repair shops; or by creating forward and backward link- ages. 7. Provide contacts with overseas banks, markets, and supply sources that would otherwise remain unknown. 8. Train domestic managers and technicians. 9. Employ domestic labor, especially in skilled jobs. 10. Generate tax revenue from income and corporate profits taxes. 11. Enhance efficiency by removing impediments to free trade and factor movement. 12. Increase national income through increased specialization and economies of scale. 14 Sources for these two sections are M ¨ uller (1979:151–178); Streeten (1973:1–14); Lall (1974:41–48); and Buffie (1993:639–667). P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 538 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development The costs of MNCs. Some economists and third-world policy makers have questioned whether MNC benefits exceed costs. These critics charge that MNCs have a negative effect on the developing country because they 1. Increase the LDC’s technological dependence on foreign sources, resulting in less technological innovation by local workers. 2. Limit the transfer of patents, industrial secrets, and other technical knowledge to the subsidiary, which may be viewed as a potential rival (Adikibi 1988:511– 526). For example, Coca-Cola left India in 1977 rather than share its secret formula with local interests (although in 1988–89 it reentered India, but without sharing its formula, to forestall dominance by Pepsi Cola’s minority-owned joint venture). 3. Enhance industrial and technological concentration. 4. Hamper local entrepreneurship and investment in infant industries. 5. Introduce inappropriate products, technology, and consumption patterns (see Nafziger, 2006b:Box 15-2, “Infant Feeding and the Multinationals”). 6. Increase unemployment rates from unsuitable technology (see Chapter 9). 7. Exacerbate income inequalities by generating jobs and patronage and producing goods that primarily benefit the richest 20 percent of the population. 8. Restrict subsidiary exports when they undercut the market of the parent com- pany. 9. Understate tax liabilities by overstating investment costs, overpricing inputs transferred from another subsidiary, and underpricing outputs sold within the MNC to another country. 10. Distort intrafirm transfer prices to transfer funds extralegally or to circumvent foreign exchange controls. 11. Require the subsidiary to purchase inputs from the parent company rather than from domestic firms. 12. Repatriate large amounts of funds – profits, royalties, and managerial and service fees – that contribute to balance of payments deficits in the years after the initial capital inflow. 13. Influence government policy in an unfavorable direction (for example, excessive protection, tax concessions, subsidies, infrastructure, and provision of factory sites). 14. Increase foreign intervention in the domestic political process. 15. Divert local, skilled personnel from domestic entrepreneurship or government service. 16. Raise a large percentage of their capital from local funds having a high oppor- tunity cost. On the last point, Ronald M ¨ uller’s (1979:151–178) evidence from Latin Amer- ica indicated that MNCs contribute only 17 percent, and local sources 83 percent, of the financial capital. However, M ¨ uller includes as local capital the subsidiary’s reinvested earnings and depreciation allowances. If this source is excluded, local financing accounts for 59 percent of total capital. Still, if the figure is representative P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 15. Balance of Payments, Aid, and Foreign Investment 539 of developing countries as a whole, MNCs contribute less than generally believed. Moreover, even if local individuals and financial institutions contribute only 20 to 30 percent, this amount represents substantial funds that invested elsewhere might better meet the country’s social priorities. Southern Africa illustrates MNC cost. Between 1960 and 1985, almost half the Western MNC investment in Africa was in the Republic of South Africa, supporting not only apartheid there but also harming the neighboring countries’ development. The MNCs and the Pretoria government viewed South Africa as the core for their expanding activities throughout other parts of southern Africa, which provided labor, a market, and raw materials. The MNCs with subsidiaries also in South Africa’s neighboring countries dominated their banking systems, invested much of these coun- tries’ financial capital in South Africa, shipped raw materials for processing from them to South Africa, and neglected their manufacturing and (sometimes) mining industries. These neighbors bought capital goods, some consumer goods, and even foodstuffs from South African MNCs. Until the 1980s, the international copper com- panies in Zambia, Zaire, Botswana, and Namibia built most fabricating factories in South Africa or the West (Seidman and Makgetla 1980). The MNCs and LDC economic interests. The MNC benefits and costs vary among classes and interest groups within a LDC population. Sometimes political elites wel- come a MNC because it benefits them through rakeoffs on its contract, sales of inputs and services, jobs for clients, and positions on the boards of directors (even though the firm harms the interests of most of the population). However, as political power is dispersed, elites may have to represent a more general public interest. Since the early 1970s, there has been a shift in bargaining power away from the MNCs to third-world governments, which have increased their technical and economic expertise and added alternative sources of capital and technology. An increasing share of MNC investment is in joint ventures with LDC government or business. And LDCs have appropriated more of the monopoly rents from public utilities and mineral production. In the 1970s, the most visible change was the shift in the ownership of OPEC oil concessions from the international oil companies to OPEC member governments (see Chapter 13). Moreover, as a result of increasing LDC restrictions, some of the MNC role has shifted from equity investment, capital ownership, and managerial control of overseas facilities to the sale of technology, management services, and marketing. As LDCs become more selective in admitting MNCs, and more effective at bargaining, they increase the benefits and reduce the costs of MNCs (Streeten 1981:308–315). Some economists, however, would argue that, since the mid-1980s, the bargaining power has shifted back somewhat to MNCs. Under IMF stabilization loans and IMF- World Bank adjustment loans, LDCs have faced pressures to privatize and open their economies to foreign capital investment, policies that provide more opportunities for DC-based multinational companies. Alternatives to MNC technology transfer. The LDCs can receive technology from MNCs without their sole ownership. Joint MNC–local country ventures can help P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 540 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development LDCs learn by doing. Yet frequent contractual limits on transferring patents, industrial secrets, and other technical knowledge to the subsidiary, which may be viewed as a potential rival, may hamper learning benefits. Turnkey projects , in which foreigners for a price provide inputs and technology, build plant and equipment, and assemble the production line so that locals can initiate production at the “turn of a key,” are usually more expensive and rarely profitable in LDCs (which usually lack an adequate industrial infrastructure). Other arrangements include management con- tracts, buying or licensing technology, or (more cheaply) buying machinery in which knowledge is embodied. The late-19th-century Japanese government, which received no foreign aid, introduced innovations by buying foreign technology or hiring foreign experts directly. More recently, in the 1980s, the Chinese government-owned Jialing Machinery Factory in Chongqing improved the engineering of its motorcycles sub- stantially by buying technical advice, machines, and parts, and licensing technology from Japan’s Honda Motor Company. Additionally, nonmarket sources of foreign knowledge include imitation, trade journals, and technical and scientific exchange, as well as feedback from foreign buyers or users of exports – all virtually costless (Nafziger 1986b:1–26; Nordquist 1987:66–71; see also Fransman 1986:11–14, who indicates major modes of transferring knowledge through the market). Sanjaya Lall’s (1985:76) conclusion is sensible: The correct strategy then must be a judicious and careful blend of permitting TNC [MNC] entry, licensing and stimulation of local technological effort. The stress must always be – as it was in Japan – to keep up with the best practice technology and to achieving production efficiency which enables local producers (regardless of their origin) to compete in world markets. This objective will necessitate TNC presence in some cases, but not in others. LOANS AT BANKERS’ STANDARDS In the 1960s, the LDC balance on goods and services deficit was financed primar- ily by flows from official or semiofficial sources in the form of grants, concessional loans, and market loans. Private finance during the 1960s consisted mainly of sup- pliers’ credits and direct foreign investment. Commercial bank lending increased in the decade after 1967. As pointed out earlier, private loans fell during most of the 1980s, increased during the early 1990s, but fell again during the late 1990s through 2003. Nonconcessional loans from abroad finance a deficit in the balance on goods and services account. For LDCs, the ratio of official aid to commercial loans declined for a decade and a half after 1970: from 1.40 in 1970 to 0.66 in 1973 to 0.55 in 1975 to 0.36 in 1978 to 0.23 in 1984. Subsequently, the ratio of official aid to commercial loans rose from 0.23 in 1984 to 0.33 in 1987 to 0.47 in 1990 and 0.43 in 1994 to 0.95 in 2002. The increasing trend after the mid-1980s mostly reflected the fall in private lending rather than substantial growth in concessional assistance. By the late 1980s and early 1990s, low-income countries, with more than twice the population of middle-income countries, received twice the official assistance that middle-income countries did, in contrast to the 1970s, late 1990s, and early years of the 21st century, P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 15. Balance of Payments, Aid, and Foreign Investment 541 when aid was relatively evenly divided among the country categories. However, all but a small fraction of commercial loans were to middle-income countries with high credit ratings (World Bank 1980i; OECD 1981; OECD 1982; World Bank 1981i:49– 63; Overseas Development Council 1982a:215–37; Overseas Development Council 1982b:225–46; IMF 1988d:96–109; IMF 1995d:161–67; OECD 2002b). Two sources of lending fell in the late 1990s and early years of the 21st century: (1) private lending as commercial bankers became unwilling to finance in the face of debt rescheduling and default (see Chapter 16), recent nonperforming loans, and more selective lending by individual banks, and (2) official (or officially supported) export credit finance (a part of short-term borrowing), and interest rates for bank finance fell. However, one source of local LDC funding is expanding – local lending by multi- national banks with headquarters in DCs. Affiliate banks of the major DCs in the Group of 10 15 are increasingly lending in local currency, a trend that could reduce LDC debt in foreign currency. The local currency claims of G-10 bank affiliates in LDCs shot up from $30 billion in 1983 to $130 billion in 1996 to $490 billion in 2002, increasing the proportion of these affiliates’ claims on LDCs in local currency from 7 percent in 1983 to 20 percent in 1996 to 68 percent in 2002 (World Bank 2003e:51). This decreases currency mismatches in LDCs, a phenomenon in which banks hold assets in local currency and incur liabilities in foreign currency, making the banks vulnerable to losses from domestic currency depreciation. Bilateral flows. OECD official development assistance is only a part of the total net flow of resources to LDCs. As indicated earlier, 0.22 percent of the 2001 GNP of OECD countries was foreign aid. However, additional net flows included private capital and bank loans – 0.96 percent of GNP, nonconcessional official flows – 0.04 percent of GNP, and private voluntary agencies – 0.03 percent of GNP. Thus, the total net flow was 1.25 percent of GNP (OECD 1995:C3–C4; UNCTAD 2003:4). The Eurocurrency market. Eurodollars are dollars deposited in banks outside the United States, often by U.S. banks. More generally, Eurocurrency deposits are in cur- rencies other than that of the country where the bank (called a Eurobank) is located. The Eurobank system began in the early 1950s when the Soviet Union, using the U.S. dollar for international trade and fearing the U.S. government might block its deposits in U.S. banks, transferred its dollars to English banks. These (and subsequently other European) banks could lend these dollars to MNCs, banks, governments, and other borrowers. Banks increased their profits by avoiding national exchange controls, reserve requirements, and bank interest ceilings, and depositors were attracted by receiving higher interest rates. In the mid-1990s, dollars comprised two-thirds of the more than $8 trillion deposits in this unregulated financial market, which is located in Europe (London, Zurich, Paris, Amsterdam, and Luxembourg), Hong Kong, 15 The G-10, like the Big 10 conference, consists of 11 : Belgium, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States. P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 542 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development Singapore, Tokyo, Kuwait, Nassau, Panama, Grand Cayman, Bahrain, and (in 1981 after U.S. banks could accept Eurodeposits) New York City. Eurobanks have played a role in lending to LDCs, including recycling petrodollars to oil-importing LDCs in the mid-1970s. Most deposits are by private nonbanks or by central banks and other official monetary institutions. Although the absence of reserve requirements and control by national monetary authorities provides substantial potential for the multiple expansion of bank deposits (and world inflation), in practice most loan funds are deposited outside Eurobanks, thus leaking out of the system (Ethier 1988:498– 509; Fusfeld 1988:799–801; Kenen 1989:453–454, 468–470; Krugman and Obstfeld 1994:642–651; Krugman and Obstfeld 2000:650–659). Funds from multilateral agencies. In 1944, 44 nations established the World Bank , envisioned primarily as a source for loans for post–World War II reconstruction; and the IMF , an agency charged with providing short-term credit for international balance of payments deficits (see Chapter 5). Neither institution was set up to solve the financial problems of developing countries; nevertheless, today virtually all financial disbursements from the World Bank are to LDCs, and the IMF is the lender of last resort for LDCs with international payments crises. The World Bank is a well-established borrower in international capital markets, issuing bonds denominated in U.S. dollars but guaranteeing a minimal Swiss franc value when the dollar depreciates. In the early years of the 21st century, the Bank, which is the largest source of long-term developmental finance for LDCs, provided about 10 percent of the total resource flows to LDCs. It lent more than $17 bil- lion to LDC governments annually, including funds for investments such as water improvement and rural infrastructure in India, telecommunications and water sup- ply in Afghanistan, mass transit in Brazil, a college of fisheries in the Philippines, irrigation and flood control in Indonesia, construction of hospitals, schools, roads, and sewage pipes in Argentina, and a Chad–Cameroon oil pipeline (although in 2004 environmental groups and other nongovernmental organizations challenged support by major international banks, LDC governments, and LDC mining companies of the World Bank continuing to finance LDC oil and coal projects) (World Bank 2004d; World Bank Development News , various issues). Furthermore, the World Bank has used its technical and planning expertise to upgrade projects to meet banking stan- dards, has lent for development plans and economic reform, and has led in organizing consortium packages of lenders and grant givers. A World Bank affiliate, the Interna- tional Finance Corporation, has invested $4 billion annually in agencies to stimulate private enterprise, such as the Industrial Credit and Investment Corporation of India, mentioned in Chapter 14. These amounts do not include soft loans (or concessional aid) of more than $6 billion annually made by another World Bank affiliate, the International Development Association. The IMF provides ready credit to a LDC with balance of payments problems equal to the reserve tranche – the country’s original contribution of gold – or 25 percent of its initial contribution or quota. Beyond that, other credit lines include the first credit tranche, with 25 percent of the quota, granted on adoption of a program to P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 15. Balance of Payments, Aid, and Foreign Investment 543 overcome international payments difficulties; an extended facility, with 150 percent of the quota, based on a detailed medium-term program; a supplementary financing facility subsidy account, 140 percent of quota (financed by repayments from trust fund loans and voluntary contributions) to support standby arrangements for eligi- ble low-income LDCs under previous programs; a compensatory and contingency financing facility (CFF), 75 percent of quota, to finance a temporary shortfall in export earnings or excess costs of cereal imports beyond the country’s control; buffer stock financing, 50 percent of the quota, to stabilize export earnings; an oil facility, funds borrowed from oil-exporting countries to lend at competitive interest rates to LDCs with balance of payments deficits; and a subsidy account, contributed by 25 DCs and capital surplus oil exporters that makes available interest subsidies to low- income countries (Grubel 1981:531–533). To illustrate, the financial intermediation of the IMF enabled India to borrow $2.85 billion from Saudi Arabia in 1981 at an interest rate of 11 percent, compared to 18 percent in the commercial markets. Yet, between 1983 and 1985, most special funding beyond direct IMF credits dried up, with net lending to LDCs falling from $11.4 billion to $0.2 billion, reducing IMF leverage to persuade LDCs to undertake austerity in the face of internal political opposition. However, from 1986 to 1988, the IMF added a structural adjustment facility (SAF) , which provides concessional assistance as a portion of a package of medium-term macroeconomic and adjustment programs to low-income countries facing chronic balance of payments problems; added an enhanced structural adjust- ment facility , renamed the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF) , “to foster durable growth” that raises living standards for the poorest IMF members making adjustments; and restored the CFF with an average grant element of 20 percent. The first two facilities were financed by a rotating fund from recycling the IMF Trust Fund (from the sale of IMF gold) and by Japan and European countries with external sur- pluses, but not the United States, which had an international deficit and was opposed to IMF long-term concessional aid. As an example of how this aid works, in 1988, the IMF approved $85 million ($35 million as SAF and $18 million as supplemen- tary funding) for Togo, whose export earnings from cocoa, coffee, palm products, and peanuts had declined from 1985 to 1987 (Feinberg 1986:14–18; World Bank 1988i:141; IMF Survey , various issues) and, in 1996–2003, support for the initia- tive for highly indebted poor countries (HIPCs), “countries that pursue IMF- and [World] Bank-supported adjustment and reform program, but for whom traditional debt relief mechanisms are insufficient” (IMF 2004) (see Chapter 16). In 1999, in response to the Asian financial crisis of 1997–98, the IMF established Contingent Credit Lines (CCL), a precautionary defense for members with trans- parency and sound policies who might, however, be vulnerable to contagion from capital account crises in other countries. After four years of disuse, CCL was discon- tinued in 2003. Countries were reluctant to use the CCL, for fear of being labeled as subject to possible crisis! In the IMF and World Bank, the collective vote of high-income OECD countries comprises a substantial majority of the total. The U.S. view of policy for LDCs is the most dominant among high-income OECD countries. The U.S. view (Summers P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 544 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development 1998:14) corresponds closely to IMF policy, as the United States, with 17.5 percent of IMF shares, only needs a few DC allies to deny an IMF loan. Indeed, Strom Thacker’s (1999) econometrics provides “strong evidence that the political interests of the U.S. drive much of the behavior” of the IMF. Robert Barro and Jong-Wha Lee’s (2002) analysis of IMF lending, 1975 to 1999, shows that an LDC’s political proximity to the United States (that is, the percentage of times that country voted in the U.N. General Assembly along with the United States) significantly increases the proba- bility and size of an IMF loan. 16 More explicitly, U.S. voting for IMF stabilization and structural adjustment lending for LDCs is significantly related to the recipi- ent’s support of U.S. foreign policy stances. (A political and strategic motivation – to promote democracy and private enterprise and minimize Soviet influence in the third world – was important in congressional approval of President Harry Truman’s call in 1949 for U.S. “Point Four” economic assistance to LDCs.) Columbia’s Jeffrey Sachs opposes IMF and World Bank structural adjustment pro- grams in Africa, arguing that the Bretton Woods’ institutions cannot force good governance with their average of 117 loan conditions. These programs delegitimize African governments, increasing their vulnerability to overthrow, and do not empha- size diversifying production and promoting exports. The high-interest low-inflation strategies of the Fund and Bank were “suffocating economic growth” in Africa (Pan- African News Agency 1998). Chris Cramer and John Weeks (2002:43–61) evaluate how IMF and World Bank macroeconomic stabilization (monetary, fiscal, and exchange-rate policies) and structural adjustment (privatization, deregulation, wage and price decontrol, and trade and financial liberalization) programs affect economic growth and income dis- tribution. These program, almost universal among LDCs after 1979, were mostly introduced in response to chronic macroeconomic imbalances and external deficits, and required borrowing from the IMF and World Bank as lenders of last resort. The standard orthodox packages, with emphases on compressing money demand, rais- ing interest rates, and reducing the role of the state (Polack 1997:16–18), have cut economic growth and increased the probability of political instability. Barro and Lee (2002) find that, other things held constant, IMF lending has no effect on economic growth during the simultaneous five-year period but has a sig- nificantly negative effect on growth in the subsequent five years. The Brandt report even contends that the IMF’s insistence on drastic measures in short time periods imposes unnecessary burdens on low-income countries that not only reduce basis- needs attainment but also occasionally lead to “IMF riots” and even the down- fall of governments (Independent Commission on International Development Issues 1980:215–216). In 2004, the Independent Evaluation Office of the IMF stated that the PRGF’s achievements had “fallen short of the ambitious expectations set out in the original policy documents, [especially] in improving conditions in the world’s poorest 16 Roubini and Setser (2004) are critical of IMF and DC rescue packages to support bailouts of countries that owe rich countries’ creditors and banks. The two authors favor smaller packages, implying only partial bailouts that “bail in” (or require losses from) U.S. and DC creditors that make risky loans to LDCs. P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 15. Balance of Payments, Aid, and Foreign Investment 545 countries, … fail[ing] to address controversial policy issues as well as [lacking] clear benchmarks against which to monitor progress.” The report called for greater flex- ibility “to accommodate the diversity of country political and administrative sys- tems and constraints” and asked “countries to define – in a manner open to public scrutiny – their own benchmarks and objectives for improving policy-making processes” ( World Bank Development News , July 29, 2004). Paul Krugman (1999:115) criticizes the IMF for its priority, in Thailand, Indonesia, Korea, and other Asian countries undergoing crisis in 1997, on raising taxes and cutting spending to reduce budget deficits and raising interest rates, adding per- haps tongue-in-cheek that “governments [must] show their seriousness by inflicting pain on themselves.” The effect was to reduce demand, worsening the recession and feeding panic. Surely the IMF must be satisfied that a borrower can repay a loan. And there may be few alternatives to monetary and fiscal restrictions or exchange-rate devaluation for eliminating a chronic balance of payments deficit. Furthermore, as Chapters 16 and 19 indicate, the IMF’s PRDG may have recently put more emphasis on growth and efficiency and less on reducing domestic demand and attaining external balance. Moreover, although the third world’s collective vote in the IMF, based on member quotas, is 40 percent, LDCs often support DCs in laying down conditions for bor- rowing members so as not to jeopardize the IMF’s financial base. Furthermore, as Kenneth Rogoff, IMF Chief Economist, 2001–03, argues (2004:65), just because we see doctors around plagues doesn’t mean they cause them; just because IMF lending accompanies LDC austerity doesn’t mean the IMF is the cause. Other major multilateral sources of nonconcessional lending in 2002 were the Inter-American Development Bank, the Asian Development Bank, the European Union, and other regional development banks. Perverse Capital Flows: From LDCs to DCs The Nobel laureate Robert Lucas (1990:92–96) asks: “Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries?” The law of diminishing returns implies that the marginal productivity of capital is higher in a capital-scarce, labor-abundant economy such as India than in the United States, a capital abundant country. Lucas estimates that, with an Indian worker of the same quality as an American worker, India’s marginal product of capital should be 58 times as in the United States. Even when Lucas concedes that one U.S. worker, with more human capital, may be as productive as five Indian workers, India’s predicted return to capital would still be a multiple of the return of the United States. Lucas surmises that DC capital in LDCs encounters capital market imperfections and restrictions, specifically, economic institutions and policies and political risks that make it difficult to enforce international borrowing agreements. Moreover, would an MNC’s technology be the same in the headquarters and LDC affiliate? Perhaps not, as technology usually needs to be modified when shifted to a different economy and culture. Chapter 16 discusses capital flight in more detail. P1: PIG 0521829666c15 CB970/Nafziger 0 521 82966 6 October 20, 2005 13:36 546 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff (2004:53–58) have another explanation for the paradox of poor to rich capital flows: the prime role of political and credit-market risk in many LDCs. They show that the number of years a country has been in default during the last 55 to 60 years is central in explaining capital flows and per-capita income levels. Ironically, the true paradox, they indicate, may be that “too much capital … is channeled to ‘debt-intolerant’ serial defaulters.” Massive Capital Inflows to the United States The major example of counterintuitive capital inflows is that to the United States. Since the last quarter of 1985, the United States has been the world’s largest inter- national debtor. By the end of 2003, the U.S. gross external debt, a stock concept that represents the accumulation over time of international deficits, was $6,800,485 million (U.S. Treasury 2003). Indeed, in 2000, the peak year of the business cycle, the U.S. current account deficit was financed by 8 percent of the combined savings of the rest of the world! By 2003, the deficit represented 10 percent of the rest of the world’s savings (World Bank 2003e:37). How can we explain this? Because of the widespread use of the dollar for interna- tional payments and reserves, global companies and central banks have accumulated dollar assets amid the United States’ persistent balance on goods, services, and income deficit. The United States was able to do this because it has been the world’s major reserve and trading currency. Unlike Argentina, Thailand, and Nigeria, the United States has borrowed its funds in its own currency, U.S. dollars, at relatively low interest rates. As pointed out in Chapter 17, the United States has had a persistent surplus (compar- ative advantage) in the trade of services and financial assets. U.S. rapid productivity growth, at least in the 1990s, from cheaply coordinatin